The Role of Central Bank Lending Facilities in Monetary Policy - Liberty Street Economics (2024)

Helene Lee and Asani Sarkar

Editor’s note: This post was originally published on June 30, 2017. We are running it again today, August 14, in conjunction with a companion piece scheduled for August 16. An error in the table was corrected on July3.

Central bank lending facilities were vital during the financial crisis of 2007-08 when many banks and nonbank financial institutions turned to them to meet funding needs as private funding dried up. Since then, there has been renewed interest in the design of central bank lending facilities in the post-crisis period. In this post, we compare the Federal Reserve’s discount window with the lending facilities at three other major central banks: the Bank of England (BoE), the European Central Bank (ECB), and the Bank of Japan (BoJ). We observe that, relative to the other central banks, the Fed’s discount window is less integrated into the monetary policy framework. In a follow-up post, we will discuss differences in the central banks’ counterparty and collateral policies.

What Is a Standing Lending Facility?

We use “standing lending facility” (SLF) to refer to a facility that lends on a bilateral and on-demand basis rather than in the open market through scheduled auctions. The Fed’s discount window—namely the primary credit program—is an example of an SLF. As shown in the table below, SLFs go by different names: at the ECB, it is called the marginal lending facility and, at the BoJ, the complementary lending facility. The BoE uses two SLFs—the operational SLF (OSLF) and the discount window facility (DWF). The OSLF, which usually lends overnight, is used for monetary policy purposes, while the DWF lends on a longer-term basis and serves a financial stability purpose. We do not discuss emergency lending facilities since these only lend in crisis situations, and are typically designed as open market auction-based facilities rather than on-demand bilateral lending facilities.

While normally considered a financial stability tool, SLFs usually also serve a monetary policy role (see table). In their monetary policy role, SLFs limit upward pressure on interest rates by providing loans to individual institutions that might occasionally experience urgent funding needs. As such, SLFs may be used to set a ceiling in the interest rate corridor, as discussed below. In addition, most SLFs have a financial stability purpose, providing credit to the financial sector broadly during crises. In this post, we focus on the SLF’s role in maintaining the interest rate corridor, where there is a difference between the Fed’s discount window and the SLFs of the other central banks.

The Role of Central Bank Lending Facilities in Monetary Policy - Liberty Street Economics (2)

Standing Lending Facility Rates as Corridor Ceilings

Frameworks for implementing monetary policy are typically either corridor-type or floor-type systems, depending on the method used for keeping the overnight, interbank interest rate close to the central bank’s target.

The BoE, ECB, and BoJ have long maintained interest rate corridors. The rate on the SLF acts as the ceiling of the corridor because, in theory, no banks should be willing to borrow at a higher rate in private funding markets. The interest rate paid by central banks at their standing deposit facility (SDF), where banks can deposit excess funds overnight, should act as the floor of the interest rate corridor (because, in theory, no banks should be willing to lend at a rate below the SDF rate). Thus, the SLF and SDF are integral parts of the monetary policy framework of the three central banks.

In contrast to the other three central banks, the Fed’s discount window has been less integrated into the monetary policy framework. This difference is partly because the Fed’s use of an interest rate corridor is more recent. Before 2003, there was no policy rate that acted as a ceiling on interest rates, since the discount window rate was kept below the federal funds target rate. This is because the discount window was intended to provide subsidized loans to institutions with temporary funding pressures. Since 2003, the rate on discount window lending—the primary credit rate—has been set above the target federal funds rate. Even so, the discount window rate has not functioned as a ceiling (with market rates often exceeding the primary credit rate) due to the stigma of borrowing from the discount window.

While the Fed has never maintained an SDF whose rate might serve as a corridor floor, in 2008 it began paying interest on reserves that banks deposit at the Fed. In theory, banks should not lend at a rate lower than the interest on reserves. In practice, the interbank rate has often traded below the interest on reserves, as some lenders are not eligible to earn interest on reserves with the Fed.

In the original Federal Reserve Act of 1913, the discount window was the only monetary policy tool, but its role in monetary policy began to decline soon thereafter. From the 1920s onward, open market operations (OMOs), involving purchases and sales of securities in the open market, became the Fed’s central monetary policy tool. Since their inception, OMOs have been successful in keeping the overnight rate close to the Fed’s target, even when interbank markets were highly volatile. It is only in recent years that the Fed has begun to adopt elements of a formal corridor system (in particular, interest on reserves).

It’s More about the Floor Since the Crisis

As overnight rates have hovered close to zero since the crisis of 2007-08, all four central banks have focused more on the floor rather than the ceiling on overnight rates. The traditional interest rate corridor continues to be maintained at the three foreign central banks, though the ECB has shifted to the use of the standing deposit rate as its main policy rate. At the Fed, a new tool (overnight reverse repos) has been implemented to help support the floor for the federal funds rate, and it appears to have been effective in keeping that rate within the target range. In our next post, we compare the counterparty and collateral policies of the Fed’s discount window with those of the other three central banks’ SLFs.

Disclaimer

The views expressed in this post are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of NewYork or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors.


The Role of Central Bank Lending Facilities in Monetary Policy - Liberty Street Economics (3)Helene Lee is a senior associate in the Federal Reserve Bank of NewYork’s Markets Group.

The Role of Central Bank Lending Facilities in Monetary Policy - Liberty Street Economics (4)Asani Sarkar is an assistant vice president in the Bank’s Research andStatistics Group.

How to cite this blog post:

Helene Lee and Asani Sarkar, “The Role of Central Bank Lending Facilities in Monetary Policy,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Liberty Street Economics (blog), June 30, 2017, http://libertystreeteconomics.newyorkfed.org/2017/06/the-role-of-central-bank-lending-facilities-in-monetary-policy.html.

I am an expert in central banking and monetary policy, and I will break down the concepts discussed in the article by Helene Lee and Asani Sarkar, originally published on June 30, 2017. I have a deep understanding of the intricacies of central bank lending facilities and the role they play in monetary policy frameworks.

Overview: The article discusses the importance of central bank lending facilities, particularly in the context of the 2007-08 financial crisis. It highlights the role of these facilities in providing vital funding to banks and nonbank financial institutions when private funding sources dried up. The comparison focuses on the Federal Reserve's discount window and its counterparts in other major central banks: the Bank of England (BoE), the European Central Bank (ECB), and the Bank of Japan (BoJ).

Standing Lending Facility (SLF): The term "standing lending facility" (SLF) is introduced, referring to a facility that lends on a bilateral and on-demand basis, rather than through scheduled auctions in the open market. The primary credit program of the Fed's discount window is given as an example of an SLF. Other central banks have similar facilities with different names, such as the marginal lending facility (ECB) and the complementary lending facility (BoJ). The BoE utilizes two SLFs: the operational SLF (OSLF) for monetary policy purposes and the discount window facility (DWF) for financial stability.

Monetary Policy Role of SLFs: SLFs are discussed in their dual roles, serving both monetary policy and financial stability. In their monetary policy role, SLFs help limit upward pressure on interest rates by providing loans to institutions facing urgent funding needs. The article emphasizes that SLFs also play a crucial role in providing credit to the financial sector during crises.

Interest Rate Corridors: The discussion moves to the frameworks for implementing monetary policy, categorized as corridor-type or floor-type systems. The BoE, ECB, and BoJ maintain interest rate corridors. The rate on the SLF acts as the ceiling of the corridor, preventing banks from borrowing at higher rates. The interest rate paid by central banks at their standing deposit facility (SDF) acts as the floor of the corridor. In contrast, the Fed's discount window historically had less integration into the monetary policy framework.

Evolution of the Fed's Discount Window: The article traces the evolution of the Fed's discount window, highlighting its changing role in monetary policy. Before 2003, the discount window rate was kept below the federal funds target rate. Since then, the primary credit rate has been set above the target federal funds rate. However, the discount window rate has not functioned as a ceiling due to the stigma associated with borrowing from it.

Focus on the Floor Since the Crisis: As overnight rates approached zero post the 2007-08 crisis, central banks shifted focus to the floor rather than the ceiling on overnight rates. The Fed introduced new tools like overnight reverse repos to support the floor for the federal funds rate.

Upcoming Comparison: The article concludes by mentioning a follow-up post that will compare the counterparty and collateral policies of the Fed's discount window with those of the other three central banks' SLFs.

In summary, the article provides a comprehensive analysis of central bank lending facilities, their roles in monetary policy, and the differences in approaches among major central banks.

The Role of Central Bank Lending Facilities in Monetary Policy - Liberty Street Economics (2024)
Top Articles
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Mr. See Jast

Last Updated:

Views: 5454

Rating: 4.4 / 5 (75 voted)

Reviews: 90% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Mr. See Jast

Birthday: 1999-07-30

Address: 8409 Megan Mountain, New Mathew, MT 44997-8193

Phone: +5023589614038

Job: Chief Executive

Hobby: Leather crafting, Flag Football, Candle making, Flying, Poi, Gunsmithing, Swimming

Introduction: My name is Mr. See Jast, I am a open, jolly, gorgeous, courageous, inexpensive, friendly, homely person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.